翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Robert Barr (schoolteacher)
・ Robert Barr (writer)
・ Robert Barr Smith
・ Robert Barra
・ Robert Barrable
・ Robert Barrat
・ Robert Barret
・ Robert Barrett
・ Robert Barrett Browning
・ Robert Barrie
・ Robert Barrie (pentathlete)
・ Robert Barrie Walker
・ Robert Barrier
・ Robert Barrington-Ward
・ Robert Barritt
Robert Barro
・ Robert Barron
・ Robert Barron (bishop)
・ Robert Barron (locksmith)
・ Robert Barrowman
・ Robert Barry
・ Robert Barry (artist)
・ Robert Barry (merchant)
・ Robert Barry (politician)
・ Robert Barry Cutler
・ Robert Barsky
・ Robert Bartczak
・ Robert Bartels
・ Robert Barth
・ Robert Bartholomew


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Robert Barro : ウィキペディア英語版
Robert Barro

Robert Joseph Barro (born September 28, 1944) is an American classical macroeconomist and the Paul M. Warburg Professor of Economics at Harvard University. The Research Papers in Economics project ranked him as the third most influential economist in the world, as of June 2013, based on his academic contributions.〔
〕 Barro is considered one of the founders of new classical macroeconomics, along with Robert Lucas, Jr. and Thomas J. Sargent. He is currently a senior fellow at Stanford University's Hoover Institution.
==Academic career==
Barro graduated with a B.S. in physics from the California Institute of Technology in 1965, where he learned under Richard Feynman, but he realized he "wouldn't be close to the top in those fields". He then turned to economics and earned a PhD from Harvard University in 1970. He first reached wide notice with a 1974 paper entitled "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?", a paper that argued that under certain assumptions, present borrowing would be matched by increased bequest to future generations to pay future taxes expected to pay the debt on the government bonds. The paper was in direct response to the Blinder-Solow results, which had implied that the long term implications of government borrowing would be compensated for by the wealth effect. This paper is among the most cited in macro-economics, and its implications of his Ricardian Equivalence are still being debated in the present.
Barro collaborated with Herschel Grossman to produce the influential article "A General Disequilibrium Model of Income," which, for many years, held the distinction of being the most cited article ever published in the ''American Economic Review.''〔Spolaore (2008).〕 The article explored the idea that disequilibrium in one market can have spillover effects to another market, creating a distinction between notional demand and effective demand. Barro and Grossman expanded on their work and produced the classic textbook ''Money, Employment, and Inflation'' in 1976.〔Kolmar, 803.〕
In 1976, he authored another influential paper, "Rational expectations and the role of monetary policy," in which he argued that information asymmetries would cause real effects as rational economic actors in response to uncertainty but not in response to expected monetary policy changes. While he has revisited the topic since then and critically appraised the paper, it was important in integrating the role of money into neo-classical economics, and in the synthesis of general equilibrium and macroeconomic models.
In 1983, he applied this information asymmetry argument to the role of central banks and concluded that central banks, to have credibility in inflation fighting, have to be locked into inflation targets that they cannot, to reduce unemployment, violate. During the 1970s, economist Arthur Okun developed the concept of the Misery Index, which Jimmy Carter publicized during his 1976 presidential campaign, and Ronald Reagan did the same in his 1980 presidential campaign. Numerous sources incorrectly credit Barro with this because of the similarity of name with his own "Barro Misery Index." Barro's version first appeared in a 1999 ''BusinessWeek'' article.
His 1984 ''Macroeconomics'' textbook remains a standard for explaining the subject, and his 1995 book, with Columbia University economist Xavier Sala-i-Martin, on ''Economic Growth'', is a widely cited and read graduate-level textbook on the theory and evidence concerning long-run economic growth. Barro's research in the 1990s was focused mainly on the theoretical and empirical determinants of growth: he gave fundamental contributions to the theory of endogenous growth (with particular attention to the links between innovation and public investment on one side and growth on the other side), and he was a pioneer in the econometric analysis of the main factors associated with growth in the modern era.〔"(Interview with Robert J. Barro )" at Francisco Marroquin University. Guatemala, May 2007〕 He was elected a Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 1988.〔(【引用サイトリンク】url=http://www.amacad.org/publications/BookofMembers/ChapterB.pdf )
Another often-cited work is a 1988 paper co-authored with Gary Becker, "A Reformulation of the Economic Theory of Fertility" published in the ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'', which is influential in thinking about "infinite time horizon" modelling.
In the last decade, Barro has begun investigating the influence of religion and popular culture on political economy, working with his wife Rachel McCleary.
Barro believes that the Keynesian multiplier is less than one. He believes that for every dollar the government borrows and spends, spending elsewhere in the economy falls by almost the same amount.
Barro's work has been central to many of the economic and public policy debates of the last 30 years, including business cycle theory, growth theory, the neo-classical synthesis and public policy. Barro is (doctor ''honoris causa'' ) from Universidad Francisco Marroquin.
Finally, Barro has been an outspoken opponent of stimulus spending, calling Obama's stimulus bill "garbage" and "the worst bill since the 1930s."

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Robert Barro」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.